(This is a summary of my views on "currency wars" that was the topic of the recent panel discussion at SIBOS in which I participated)
A standard ploy of magicians and politicians is called
misdirection. The audience is distracted from the real movement by a feint.
“Currency war,” which has become the title of books, articles and conferences,
is such a misdirection.
Some officials, notably Brazilian Finance Minister Guido Mantega,
have been leading the charge that through pursuing unorthodox monetary policy,
the U.S. has sparked powerful forces that destabilize the emerging market
economies through capital flows, driving the currencies sharply higher.
Emerging Markets
It is indisputable that international capital movement is
volatile and that the accommodative monetary policy in the U.S., and other
developed economies, has shifted interest rate differentials more in favor of
emerging markets. This shift has likely spurred private capital flows. That is both
a common ground and a point of departure.
Capital inflows into the emerging markets are driven by a
number of considerations, not just interest rate differentials. Consider, for
example that growth differentials and higher returns on investment have also been
attracting investment flows, especially in recent years.
The general investment climate is shaped in part by the risk
appetite of investors. The risk-on and risk-off matrix has shifted in recent
years, not as much by the pursuit of U.S. monetary policy as by the shifting
response to the European debt crisis.
In a recent speech, Federal Reserve Chairman Bernanke cited
research by the IMF and others that concluded that monetary policies of the
advanced economies were not the dominant drivers of private savings into
emerging markets. He went further and noted that capital flows into emerging
markets have slowed considerably over the past couple of years, and even as the U.S.,
Europe and Japan continued to ease monetary policy.
If the cry of “currency war” is a misdirection, what exactly
is it trying to distract our attention from? Many emerging market countries
want to have currency valuations that economists argue are below fair value.
They do so to promote exports and bypass domestic structural obstacles to
growth.
Under-valued currencies in and of themselves may attract
foreign capital flows anticipating currency appreciation. Moreover,
purposefully weak currency strategies often leave developing countries more
vulnerable to inflation, and more sensitive to the monetary policies of other
countries.
Currency Flexibility
The U.S., through numerous administrations, and in various
declarations of the Group of Seven industrial nations, has consistently advocated
greater currency flexibility. Such flexibility would allow greater independence
in the conduct of monetary policy and offer greater insulation from external
developments.
This, of course, applies not only to Brazil, but also to China,
the world’s second largest economy. A more flexible currency regime would help
officials refocus their economy from one driven by external demand to one led
by domestic consumption. It would allow the Chinese people to enjoy a greater share
of their country’s economic success and prowess.
Brazil’s finance minister claimed that the U.S. was being
selfish in pursuing monetary policy without taking into account the impact of
such a policy on other countries. Yet, the real selfishness and
beggar-thy-neighbor policies are not the easing of the U.S. and other advanced
economies, but the reluctance of many emerging countries to allow their
currencies to appreciate in the face of stronger growth, capital inflows and
larger reserve positions.
Monetary Policy
Even if there are costs for developing countries from the
easy monetary policy of the advanced economies, there are also benefits. Part
of the reason why the economies of many developing countries have slowed is
that their exports to the U.S. and Europe have decreased as those economies
have decelerated.
Easier monetary policy, which has taken on an unorthodox
characteristic given that policy rates are near zero, is meant to help fuel a
recovery in aggregate demand. Stronger U.S. and European growth would stimulate
trade as well as underpin growth in emerging markets.
Aggressive monetary policy in the face of weak domestic
economies is not the equivalent of a currency war. To the contrary, the fact
that some developing economies insist on having under-valued currencies is more
directly recognizable as shots in a currency war. Such policies can be
associated with costs, such as greater sensitivity to inflation and limits on
the independence of their own monetary policies. There are various drivers of
capital flows to emerging markets, and those capital flows do not appear to be
correlated with U.S. or European monetary policies.
It is interesting to note that, for the better part of the
past four months, as the Federal Reserve signaled, and then pursued QE3+, the
European Central Bank announced its Outright Market Transactions and the Bank
of Japan expanded its asset purchase program in both September and October, the
Brazilian real has been largely flat. The dollar has largely been confined to a BRL2.00-BRL2.05
trading range, though has strengthened recently.
Investors recognize that there are a number of emerging
market countries, such as Mexico, Poland, Turkey and South Africa, which have
embraced currency flexibility to a greater extent. They have increased the
capacity of their own capital markets to absorb inflows as well as absorbing a
greater part of their own domestic savings.
U.S. Dollar and
Chinese Renminbi
There is another dimension to debate about currency wars.
Many observers argue that the U.S. dollar is in an inexorable decline and that
it will be increasingly supplanted by the Chinese renminbi. On the other hand, China
itself is not above deflecting criticism of its rigid currency regime by
criticizing the international monetary regime and the role of the dollar.
The internationalization of the Chinese renminbi has been
more bluster than substance. The role of the renminbi in the world economy
remains minor. The numerous swap lines that China arranged with many developing
countries, which captured the imagination of many critics of the U.S., have not
been used. Few countries have chosen to add the renminbi to their reserves.
The Dim Sum market, the offshore renminbi market in Hong
Kong, a special administrative region of China, is dominated by Chinese state-owned
companies, banks and property companies. Renminbi in Hong Kong is not fungible
with renminbi onshore. The currency requires special authority to be used
within China itself. Outside of Chinese trade with Hong Kong, most of Chinese
trade continues to be conducted in U.S. dollars.
There has been some diversification of reserves away from
the dollar and euro in recent years. However, it has not gone to the Chinese
renminbi, but to the Australian and Canadian dollars. The kind of transparency
and flexibility that an international currency requires still seems beyond the
ken of Chinese officials.
More Rhetoric than
Politics
Currency wars then, in either expression, seem to be more in
the realm of rhetoric than politics. There has been a long and sustained push
from the developed countries to get emerging markets to embrace more flexible
currency regimes. The adoption of unorthodox monetary policy by the U.S.,
Europe and Japan may, on the margins, increase such pressure but few have
capitulated. Instead, they have developed a host of other tools, such as
macro-prudential policies, to blunt the impact. China may one day provide the
world’s key currency, but that day is not in sight, and the role of the dollar
as the numéraire continues.
The Misdirection of Currency Wars
Reviewed by Marc Chandler
on
November 14, 2012
Rating: