The European Central Bank meets tomorrow.
The focus is on the details of the asset-backed securities and covered bond
plan that was announced last month.
There are three key issues related to this new
initiative: What instruments will be purchased, how much will
be bought, and how long will the purchase program last?
The ECB will buy the safest tranche of the
asset-backed securities. The initial proposal that it could buy
riskier tranches if guaranteed by national governments was quickly rebuffed not
only by Germany, which has been critical of the purchase plan, but also
France.
Since the crisis erupted several years ago,
the ECB has reduced the quality of the assets it will accept as collateral,
including ABS. Greek and Cypriot ABS still does not meet even
these relaxed criteria. There was a report this week that intimated an
effort to make an exception of these two countries. However, this seems
unlikely as such exceptions are not fair and would probably not have sufficient
support.
Indeed, it could have very well been an
intentional leak to toughen the resolve of German and creditor nation
resistance. Recall that the decision to cut interest rates last month and
the purchase program was not unanimous. Draghi referred to it as a
"comfortable majority". This does not sound as if Germany was
the sole dissenter.
After the low use of the new Targeted Long
Term Repo Operation facility, there was initially some thought that this
would increase the pressure on the ECB to "shock and awe" with the
"modalities" of its asset purchase program. A Reuters polls
found a consensus expectation that the ECB would buy 200 bln euros of ABS and
covered bonds over the next 12 months. In a poll shortly after last month's
ECB meeting, the consensus was for a 300 bln euro program.
We see some risk that the ECB does not
announce the size of its purchase program. This would maximize it
operational flexibility. Once it announces the criteria of its purchases,
the market can deduce the potential size. This is true of covered bonds
as well. The prior two covered bond purchase programs were 40-60 bln
euros, which would be the lion's share of the outstanding supply.
One significant wrinkle is that ABS and
covered bonds have been used extensively for collateral at the ECB.
For example, banks retain part of the covered bonds, but these are used as an
emergency liquidity backstop and the banks may be reluctant to part with
these. The weakness of the housing market through much of the eurozone and the asset encumbrance rules, argue against
a surge in new supply of covered bonds.
Draghi had indicated desire to lift the ECB's
balance sheet back toward 2012 levels. We have cautioned against
making a fetish of this target. It is not clear that it is an official
policy target; more a desire, perhaps, than a commitment. Still, some
argue that this is not quantitative easing,
as if quantitative easing has an agreed upon definition. In the US,
for example, Bernanke did not call the Fed's long-term asset purchases
quantitative easing, but credit easing.
Some argue that to qualify as QE, sovereign
bonds need to be purchased. The Bank of Japan buys government bonds but also buys REITs, ETFS, and
corporate bonds. The different policy responses in among the major
economies is partly a function of different types of capitalisms. The US
and UK, for example, rely more on markets to distribute capital, but Japan and
the euro area remain bank-centric.
Not only is the definition of QE not agreed
upon, but its purpose has varied. When long-term assets were initially purchased, it was to alleviate financial market stress by pushing down interest
rates and displacing investors out of risk-free assets. Its goal was later
broadened to include resisting deflationary impulses, and then used to stimulate
the real economy.
The goal of the ECB's asset purchase plan is
to arrest disinflation, re-anchor inflation expectations, and help boost
lending to small and medium businesses and households. While
Draghi, like all central bankers, are loath to limit policy options a priori,
those looking for a hint that the ECB is considering a sovereign bond purchase
scheme will likely be disappointed. It is not just because of German (and
creditor) opposition. The ECB has overruled German objections several times,
including the initial bond purchase plan (SMP), the Outright Monetary
Transactions, and again with the recent rate cuts and asset purchase
plan.
It is not just the legal hurdles, as the
market awaits the European Court of Justice ruling on the OMT, for which the
Bundesbank's Weidmann testified against. Weidmann himself previously
indicated that under certain conditions QE might be acceptable. There are non-political and non-legalistic
reasons to be suspicious of a sovereign-based QE. What is the
point? Eight eurozone members
have negative 2-year yields, including Ireland and Slovakia.
Germany's 10-year bond yield is below 90 bp. Italian and Spanish
sovereign yields are at record lows though debt levels are at record
highs.
Of the ECB's challenges, high sovereign bond
yields are not among them. It is not clear that buying sovereign
bonds will boost inflation. The weaker euro may have a greater
impact on boosting price pressures than lower nominal interest rates. The
link between sovereign rates and rates paid by households and SMEs is not very
tight.
During the Great Depression, when the US was
also more bank-centric, the Federal Reserve dis-intermediated the banks.
They moved into the breach created by banks either unwilling or unable to
lend. The Federal Reserve lent directly to small and medium sized
businesses. While the ECB does not have that experience in its short
history, some of the national central banks have made loans to
businesses.
In a
larger sense, what ails the eurozone might not be amenable to monetary policy. And the only reason that monetary policy is
being over active is that fiscal policy is frozen. The cult of austerity means that most
countries do not have scope to use fiscal policy. Those countries that have the scope, like
Germany, do not have the will. The grand
coalition government in Germany has agreed to deliver a balanced budget next
year.
The recent
and sharp decline in the yen is expected to reignite the upward pressure on
prices. The decline in the euro may
do the same for the eurozone. Earlier
this year, we suggested that the ECB should consider taking a page out of the
Swiss National Bank’s play book. When it
wanted to ease policy, the SNB was constrained from a QE operation by the lack
of sufficient domestic bonds. It bought
foreign bonds.
Rather
than take the controversial step of buying member bonds, the ECB could buy foreign bonds. It would not have to
do a large size. An announcement to buy
a relatively small amount of Treasuries is well within the ECB’s mandate and would have a dramatic effect.
It would
likely annoy US officials. The
Treasury’s report earlier this year urged foreign officials not to buy US
government bonds. This, they argued, prevents
the adjustment process to which the G20 are committed. A weaker euro simply borrows (or steals,
depending on your vantage point) growth from elsewhere. It does not create the conditions for
sustainable growth, the way that structural reform can. However,
if the ECB’s foreign bond purchases were
part of a larger commitment to pro-growth policies and structural reforms, it
would likely be more palatable.
What is the ECB to Do?
Reviewed by Marc Chandler
on
October 01, 2014
Rating: