(I am about to begin a two-week business trip to Beijing, Hong Kong and Tokyo. I still intend to write but the timing will be more sporadic.)
This Great Graphic was posted by Eric Nelson, the managing editor of the Chamber of Commerce's Above the Fold publication. It shows many of the different components of the 737 single-aisle airplane and where they are sourced.
This Great Graphic was posted by Eric Nelson, the managing editor of the Chamber of Commerce's Above the Fold publication. It shows many of the different components of the 737 single-aisle airplane and where they are sourced.
There is a
complex supply chain that stretches from Australia, through Asia (e.g., Japan,
South Korea, and China) through Europe (France, Sweden, the UK, and Italy). It extends into Canada and several
US states as well. Some of the foreign-sourced components come from
Boeing's own facilities abroad, like the
moveable trailing edge of the wings, which are
built by its factory in Australia, or the landing gear doors from
Canada.
The intrafirm trade illustrates the complexity of
the situation. Perhaps in the 19th century, when
our current framework for understanding trade emerged, a company in one country
would export its goods to a foreign entity. However, this has changed.
Intrafirm trade appears may account for around a third of US exports and
2/5 of US imports.
The 19th-century approach was to focus on the
movement of goods across national frontiers. In the 21st century that is not
sufficient to inform trade policy or understand the global linkages. Ownership
of those goods moving across borders is important on various levels.
Should that
wing component made by Boeing in Australia and shipped to the US be considered
an import? Or is what is really going on is that Boeing has a virtual factory, and it simply
moved the component from one side of the factory
floor to the other? Imagine a trade policy that ignored the role of intrafirm trade. A tariff, for example, on
imports from Australia, for example, could hurt some US domestic producers.
Until last year, Boeing was committed to assembling all
their planes in the United States. Then two things happened, and
neither involved the fluctuation of the dollar. First, Congress had
chosen not to renew the Ex-Im Bank's charter. Partly because Boeing's planes are more technology-intensive, they are
typically more expensive than its competitors (though cheaper, reportedly, over
the lifetime of the plane). The Ex-Im Bank had facilitated,
through cheap credit Boeing sales, Some critics, in fact, called the Ex-Im Bank
"Boeing's Bank."
The second
thing that happened was China President Xi led a trade delegation to the US and
went on a shopping spree. It agreed to buy 300 of Boeing's 737
plane, which is one of the largest orders ever. It is not clear from the
accounts how much was quid pro quo, but
Boeing agreed to construct some of the 737 planes in China under a joint
venture.
In addition to
the complexity of supply chains and the role of intrafirm
trade, another issue that is raised here
is about direct investment. Direct investment is about
ownership. It is building or buying production and/or distribution centers abroad. Direct investment has
different characteristics from portfolio investment. Buying bonds and
stocks in a foreign country is important,
and the internationalization of savings is an important feature of the our
modern world. However, the extent of direct investment is also important.
Like the planes
that will be constructed and sold in China, many, if not most, of the Japanese
brand cars on US roads today, are built in the US. At least one Japanese carmaker
exports cars from California. The importance of the stock of foreign
direct investment goes unrecognized in most narratives about trade. One
dramatic implication is that the US does not serve foreign demand by exporting,
though the US is the world's third largest exporter (behind China and Germany).
Rather US companies service foreign demand by building locally and
selling locally. The sales by the foreign affiliates of US companies sell
more than 4x more goods than are exported from the US. According to MOF
data, Japanese companies made the switch in the late-1990s, so that the sale of
its affiliates also outstrip exports.
What follows
from this is that the location of those affiliates
are not primarily in low-wage countries. That is a myth. Over half, the employment of US businesses abroad
are in high wage economies in Canada, Europe, Japan and Australia. The employment in South America and Africa are also concentrated in the relatively high
wage regions. Why? US producers want to be close to their
customers.
The impact of
the complex supply chains, intrafirm trade, and the significance of direct
investment on labor markets is beyond the scope of this post. However, a nuanced approach looks
necessary as there appears to be both competitive and complimentary linkages. It seems
that low-skilled workers abroad do compete with low-skilled workers at domestic
affiliates. However, employment of high-skilled workers abroad
compliments (as in leads to more) high skilled domestic
employment.
Disclaimer
.
Great Graphic: Non-Consensus Thinking on Trade
Reviewed by Marc Chandler
on
May 05, 2016
Rating: